Economics as a Social Science: A Review of ECONned by Yves Smith

I was going to call this review "Naked Came the Economist", but ECONned: How Unenlightened Self Interest Undermined Democracy and Corrupted Capitalism by Yves Smith of Naked Capitalist is too well written. ECONNED can be divided in two major sections. The first part deals with the flawed economic assumptions that led to the collapse of Big Shitpile and other economic fun times. The second part provides a natural history of what happened, while, at the same time, relating it to the flawed economic assumptions. To deal with the last part first, it's a very good description, although those lacking any familiarity with what has happened over the last few years might find it tough going. This isn't Smith's fault: finance, like introductory biology, has a larger glossary than introductory French (seriously, check out some textbooks).

But what really sets this book apart is the deconstruction of the neoclassical paradigm in economics in the first three chapters. Those three chapters should not only be required reading for economics majors, but for anyone interested in economic policy.

Unlike most 'Keynesians', who only turn to Keynes when everything goes to shit, Smith makes the case that the assumptions of neoclassical economics rarely, if ever pertain. Keynes' animal spirits--human irrationality (in the economic, not cognitive sense)--aren't just a property of bubble manias (e.g., tech stocks in the1990s, and the recent housing bubble). Animal spirits are always operative, and often fouling up supposedly efficient markets. I hope this point--arguably the most critical--doesn't get lost, but I fear it will.

ECONned isn't merely partisan bashing (although given the total embrace of neoclassicism by conservatives, they do get dinged a lot more): Paul Krugman comes under criticism too. The first major criticism is the failure by neoclassicists to understand the relevant economic 'natural history': that is, those stupid fucking natural history facts do matter. In Krugman's case, he gets whacked, and rightly so, for claiming that the run up in oil prices wasn't driven by speculation (it was), since he didn't understand how the oil futures market is structured. Conservatives get whacked due to all sorts of ridiculousness too--there's an entire appendix dedicated to bashing one of the most basic neoclassicist models.

But I think the other great insight (other than the universality of animal spirits) is how economics as a discipline, and the intellectual edifice of that discipline, is precarious at best. Smith several times describes economics as a social science, not a hard science. In her opinion, economics failed to catch the bubble, and even contributed to it due to a slavish devotion to mathematical theory (e.g., Gaussian copula functions), when it should have been focused much more on the sociology of economic phenomena (which makes sense given the importance of animal spirits). The false security endowed by supposedly hard (dare we say tumescent?) science blinded much of the discipline to the reality on the ground, whereas some old-fashioned fact gathering might have helped a lot more. A sociologist interviewing buyers and sellers in the CDS and CDO markets would have done a world of good.

In short, this is a superb book, if at times a bit jargon laden, and should be recommended reading for anyone who cares about economic policy and theory.

More like this

Paul Krugman's analysis of Milton Friedman's intellectual legacy is one of the best articles I've read recently. Krugman not only paints a balanced portrait of Friedman's accomplishments - great economist, bad popularizer - but ably summarizes the rival tensions in 20th century economics. It's all…
Before I got into genomics, I spent some time in science and health policy. On a couple occasions, I was invited to participate in a round table/white paper thingee where we were supposed to offer suggestions to NIH and other funding agencies. We would make recommendations, program officers would…
A dissertation committee member who will remain nameless once told me, "Mike, in the end, it all comes down to those stupid fucking natural history facts." This might have been the only worthwhile thing said committee member ever told me. More about this in a bit. Anyway, I bring this up because…
A while ago, economist Paul Krugman described the institutional loss of knowledge in the discipline of economics: And the latter group, the equilibrium macro side, was so convinced of the logical correctness of its position that schools dominated by that view stopped teaching demand-side economics…

Economists famously split their study into "positive" and "normative", and go into a hypocritical divide by teaching the positive while practicing the normative. What's fascinating is they generally do not recognize the fact that anthropologists, for example, split economics into "formalist" and "substantive" schools, and it's only within the "formalist" moiety that professional economists have any awareness of their subject.

Of course, it does not help that a lot of the anthropologists involved can't hack Econ 101, giving the professional economists a ready-made excuse.

By william e emba (not verified) on 08 Apr 2010 #permalink

Mike,

Can you summarize Smith's counterargument to Krugman re: oil prices driven by speculation? I don't have access to the book, but I am interested in seeing if it really is as devastating as you make it out to be.

By Tyler DiPietro (not verified) on 10 Apr 2010 #permalink

Tyler:

The best I can find is this (linked to by Yves Smith). I find it... unconvincing. It essentially says that oil futures markets aren't just "bets" but are actually used to set the price of oil. I have no idea when we became so fixated on the "betting" aspect of futures markets that this comes as some sort of a revelation. What is missing is a sensible explanation of how a speculator (or high volume of speculators) can do three things on the huge, liquid futures markets:

1) Drive up the price of oil.
2) Keep it increasing over a long period of time.
3) Not only avoid losing their shirts, but actually make enough money to make it worthwhile.

Ideally, the explanation should be possible to draw using supply and demand graphs or written in equations. I've seen a lot of hand-waving that sounds good but falls apart when you realize that they cannot physically be drawn with graphs that meet the slope and concavity requirements of an actual market.

The description of the "squeeze" on the spot market makes sense, but that's why we have a futures market. I simply don't follow what these people are trying to get at. How is the oil futures market so different from other futures markets that it doesn't obey the same basic rules?

By Troublesome Frog (not verified) on 11 Apr 2010 #permalink