Carbon reduction: Principle and politics

There's a lot of excitement about ethanol lately, and the President will undoubtedly tell us more about ethanol tonight. But stopping the increase in atmospheric greenhouse gases will take more than just changing how we fuel our cars.

A paper published in 2004 by Pacala and Socolow lays out a range of options for carbon reduction. The options span several major categories: promoting energy efficiency and conservation, shifting from coal to natural gas for electricity production, technological capture and storage of carbon dioxide, expanding energy production from nuclear fission, switching to renewable electricity and fuels, and sequestration in forests and agricultural soils.

While a focus on renewable energy sources is important, it's worth remembering that even ethanol boosters are only talking about replacing a third of the gasoline currently burned within 30 years. And many people consider that overly optimistic. Pacala and Socolow argue that pulling seven major policies from the options above, each reducing carbon emissions by 1 gigaton/year, roughly 15% of current emissions.

Several of those wedges can come from renewable energy, but not all seven. Ending tropical clearcutting and planting new tropical forests could produce one of the wedges, for instance. A 1996 IPCC study found that one wedge worth of reductions could come from implementing more efficient practices in commercial and residential buildings globally. Doubling fuel efficiency of cars would generate one wedge.

Some of those techniques could come from government mandates, especially fuel economy standards. Others would be difficult to enforce directly. It's hard to imagine compulsory wind turbine construction, or a requirement to make buildings more efficient.

Policies do exist which would encourage people and businesses to move towards these solutions on their own, and I'll lay those options out below the fold.

One big policy that gets tossed around a lot is a carbon cap and trade system. Kyoto was based on such a system, Europe has instituted carbon trading between EU members and California is moving towards one also. Of the many climate bills circulating in Congress, several propose some version of such a system. The basic principle of such a program is that you establish fixed limits on carbon emissions, and allocate a share of those emissions to particular companies or facilities. Right now, the European system covers industrial facilities, it will expand in various ways over time. An individual user who implements reforms allowing less emissions can sell the excess to a company that is in danger of exceeding its limits. By gradually lowering the total allocation, you make those tradeable credits more valuable, making conservation more and more cost-effective.

Kevin Vranes, our already missed Scienceblogging buddy, has a nice discussion of a US government report on one proposed cap-and-trade plan being debated in the Senate. In that analysis, the Energy Information Agency found that the rate of growth in energy emissions might decrease, but actual emissions would not over the time scales examined. Cutting the growth rate in half is nice, but it isn't enough. It appears that this plan is limited by a very long delay before emissions are actually capped, and by a "safety valve," allowing energy suppliers to buy exemptions from the caps. The plan also limits carbon "upstream," with the petroleum or coal seller, for instance, rather than at the point of emission. That may reduce incentives for power plants to sequester carbon at the time of combustion, and its effect on urging power generators or car drivers to switch to more efficient fuels will be comparable to a carbon tax, rather than giving them a clear incentive to keep track of their own carbon emissions. It's hard to say whether other plans before Congress, plans that would limit carbon emissions at the source rather than upstream, for instance, would be more effective.

The basic concept of a cap-and trade system is sound. We discussed an application of the principle in discussing fishing quotas a while back, and a coalition of industry and environmental groups have endorsed the concept as well. There are even hints that the President will roll out a version of cap-and-trade, though the White House Press Secretary denies it.

The advantage of that system is that it doesn't require the government to pick a winner, instead encouraging industry could seek and find the best solutions available now, upgrading and intensifying their changes over time. The proposal the EIA analyzed would have allocated revenue from selling quotas into a trust fund that would be spent on addition research on new energy technology. While they couldn't estimate the effects of that reinvestment on the economy, it's not implausible to think that such research could produce new industries, just as Space Race and Cold War investment in technology and training laid the groundwork for the Internet and the personal computer. The Apollo Alliance has suggested that a major push for energy independence within ten years would generate jobs and grow the economy.

A major focus of any such program would be on electrical industry. Since the grid itself is agnostic to the energy source, individual landowners could, in principle, build solar generators or wind turbines and sell energy back onto the grid. Since individual landowners are unlikely to generate enough energy to consistently supply all their own power needs (the wind does stop blowing, and the sun does set), they would still have to buy power from the utilities. Different states have different rules for how this could work. Alternative energy advocates generally favor something called "net metering," in which producers would roll back their electric meter with the power they generate, getting a check from the utility if they produce more power than they consume.

Kansas, a state with huge potential for wind energy, is one of 15 states that does not currently permit net metering. That means that wind development in Kansas is all undertaken by utilities. What could be a new revenue stream to rural economies is taken out of play by that policy decision. While Kansas could be an energy exporter, we instead are lagging behind other states in wind generation.

While energy generation tends to be the focus of our discussions about climate change and energy policy, there's a lot that could be done to reduce energy demand. Compact fluorescent bulbs are getting cheaper and work well in most places where we currently use incandescents. Switching to CFLs would save lots of money and reduce greenhouse gas emissions. Adding insulation, upgrading outdated appliances, putting our computers to sleep when they aren't in use, all of these could cut energy demand. Putting together pre-packaged energy efficiency upgrades could create new exports to the developing world, and would help them leapfrog over the part of our industrial growth that set the stage for the problem we now face.

The government might have a hard time forcing compliance with these matters, but can take some steps. Raising vehicle fuel economy is one important step, one in which we are fallling behind other industrial nations, as An Inconvenient Truth pointed out. This reduces the competitive advantage of American auto manufacturers at home and abroad. Raising fuel economy standards would serve to protect American jobs, by ensuring that all manufacturers have to bear the same cost in terms of research, development and manufacturing. Creating tax incentives for energy efficient products, grants or low-interest loans for companies to upgrade their production practices and energy efficiency would be another powerful tool. Walmart has already declared that, in order to save money, they will require their suppliers to upgrade their energy efficiency, and will loan companies the money to make changes if necessary.

Tonight, when the President talks about our "addiction to foreign oil," and the necessity of changing our energy policies, listen for these other parts of the equation. If, as in previous years, he just tells us more about ethanol and hydrogen fuel cells, he's only playing politics. That isn't and cannot be the whole story.

Coming up next: trade policy and carbon reduction. But first a diversion into Congressional minutiae.

Categories

More like this

We still aren't going to get a presidential debate devoted to science. So far, though,we have the Democratic nominee's elaborated responses to 14 questions put to him and his Republican counterpart by the Science Debate 2008 group. Here's two of Barack Obama's responses, with italicized annotation…
The Wall Street Journal polled 60 economists, and a big majority backed a carbon tax: Forty of 47 economists who answered the question said the government should help champion alternative fuels. "Economists generally are in favor of free-market solutions, but there are times when you need to…
One of the best ways to illustrate the growing societal consensus on global warming is the reaction of businesses. An alliance of conservation groups, car makers, utilities and industrial manufacturers is backing a system of cap and trade which would reduce allowable carbon emissions over several…
Energy policy is one of those nerdy things that no one pays attention to until it starts to go wrong. And that's where we stand today. Electricity demand continues to rise, as documented by this report by the Energy Information Administration. And most of that electricity is generated by coal…

Wes Jackson, of the Land Institute in Salina, has demonstrated that we can't "grow our way" out of the carbon-based fuel problem. There simply are not enough acres of farmland to do it.

I wish I had a link I could point to, but I don't. I heard him talk at length about it at a lecture at the Land Institute last fall.

Ethanol sounds good but at what cost? Shall we devote most of the corn yield to feeding our cars instead of ourselves and our livestock? One way or another it would seem that the food supply will be impacted and its effects shall reach around the globe. Growing more corn is not an answer, considering that the land needed just isn't there. But of course in a free market economy corn could become a very desirous and therefore expensive commodity, outstripping its actual worth as food to be eaten. Its not at all surprising that Bush could get excited over ethanol, there is after all a vast untapped well of money out there thats connected to its use as a fuel. Not that this is a bad thing, I just wonder at what cost.

I've seen similar arguments all over, and I suspect they are basically right. We can reduce the problem, and increases in efficiency could move us forward even faster, but replacing 50% of current gasoline usage would require ethanol from 7 times the land currently planted in corn. With the right technology, ethanol may reduce our dependence on gas, but it isn't enough. There are people who think butanol will succeed where ethanol has failed. We'll see.

I don't have time for a web search, but I do know that there is at least one, if not more, forms of algea that are rich sources of vegetable-type oil that is suitable for bio-diesel. This algea could be grown in coastal or offshore farm, as well as in the American Southwest (lots of sun and unused land out there) if a method of keeping shallow pools full of water could be devised (one idea I saw involved cutting a channel from the ocean to the desert farms, but that sounds real pricey).

By MadRocketScientist (not verified) on 23 Jan 2007 #permalink

I think there is a serious economic problem with net metering. A fairly large proportion of the cost of power to the end user is distribution cost -not production (at the power plant cost). So if
I say have net zero usage, but use the distribution system for free.
Net metering (at least with the same price both directions) won't be viable large scale.
The main thing overall is to bring the externalities into the pricing mechanism. The maximum cost for CO2 should logically be the cost for the best technology to capture/sequester it from free air. Today we have commercially available offsets for as low as $5/ton, but I suspect that is exploiting a limited low-hanging fruit resource.
I don't have a problem with putting the cost onto the producers rather than the consumers, it will be passed on, and the acounting is much simpler. Of course accounting for capture/sequestration is needed as part of the overall mechamism.

bigTom, I think you are right about net metering, and I think a lot of these systems do not roll back at the same speed that they roll forward. There's nothing to say that the utility shouldn't be able to charge something for the use of its infrastructure.